TOWARDS DEVELOPMENT-ORIENTED IP POLICY: SETTING
AN AGENDA FOR THE NEXT FIVE YEARS
The Bellagio Series on Development and Intellectual
Property Policy
At the
Rockefeller Foundation's Bellagio Study and Conference Center
on Lake Como in Northern Italy,
30 October - 2 November 2002
Description
| Background
Note | Programme
| Participants
| Documentation
Background Note
Intellectual
property rights (IPRs) have never been more economically and politically
important or controversial than they are today. Patents, copyrights,
trademarks and geographical indications are frequently mentioned
in discussions and debates on such diverse topics as public health,
agriculture, education, trade, industrial policy, biodiversity
management, biotechnology, information technology, the entertainment
and media industries, and increasingly the widening gap between
the income levels of the developed countries and the developing,
and especially least-developed, countries. There is no doubt that
an understanding of IPRs is indispensable to informed policy making
in all areas of human development including the alleviation of
poverty.
Developing
country members of the World Trade Organization (WTO) no longer
have the policy options and flexibilities developed countries
had in using IPRs to support their national development. The
Agreement on Trade-related Aspects of Intellectual Property
Rights (TRIPS) imposes minimum, relatively high, standards,
which all WTO members must follow. But, TRIPS is not the end
of the story. Significant new developments are taking place
at the international, regional and bilateral level that build
on and strengthen the minimum TRIPS standards.
Recent World
Bank estimates suggest that the costs of adopting these standards,
just in terms of financial transfers from developing to developed
countries through royalties and licence fees, will be extremely
high:
If TRIPS were fully implemented, rent
transfers to major technology-creating countries - particularly
the United States, Germany, and France - in the form of pharmaceutical
patents, computer chip designs, and other intellectual property,
would amount to more than $20 billion.
Stated baldly, and if the assumptions on which the
research is based are reliable, this means that TRIPS represents
a $20 billion plus transfer of wealth from the technology importing
nations - many of which are developing countries - to the technology
exporters - few if any of which are developing countries - that
may or may not be outweighed by future gains. While benefits are
also likely, such as through increased direct foreign investment,
these are likely to take longer to accrue and their scale is difficult
to predict. The dynamic efficiencies of stronger and more effective
IPR systems may more than make up for the administrative and enforcement
costs, as might increased direct foreign investments. Whether or
not this turns out to be true, the costs must be borne before the
benefits accrue and, for least-developed countries especially, these
are likely to be particularly onerous.
For several reasons national policy making and
international negotiating on IPRs is very difficult for developing
and especially least-developed countries. This is due to three
factors: (1) the cross-cutting nature of IPR regulation; (2) divergent
views and lack of data; and (3) the dynamic nature of international
IPR rule-making.
(1) The cross-cutting nature of IPR regulation
IPRs relate to and impact simultaneously on a
broad range of economic activities and business sectors. For example,
patents potentially affect industrial development, foreign direct
investment, access to technologies, international trade, public
health, food security, natural resource management, and sectors
such as biotechnology, pharmaceuticals, engineering and software.
Consequently, effective policy making requires the integration
of technical expertise coming from a wide range of disciplines
as well as coordinated decision-making by different government
ministries that may have little experience of working together.
This is a big challenge for many countries.
(2) Divergent views and lack of data
Informed opinion on IPRs varies widely. Some believe
that strong IPR protection and enforcement is indispensable for
a modern economy, and the stronger the better. Critics argue that
IPRs - or at least the way they are currently contoured - have
such deleterious effects as raising the prices of essential drugs
to levels that are too high for the poor to afford; limiting the
available of educational materials for developing country school
and university students; legitimising the piracy of traditional
knowledge; and undermining the self-reliance of resource-poor
farmers. Understandably, debates on these issues are polarized
and emotional. It is difficult to know where the truth lies. Policy
makers need to be able to separate out the truth from the propaganda
so that they can design IPR laws and policies that best meet the
needs of the people they represent and negotiate effectively in
future agreements. But this is far from easy. It is impossible
to calculate with any certainty the long-term impacts of TRIPS
on developing countries and their populations. It is possible
that ultimately every country will benefit. But this is pure speculation.
We can be certain, though, that developing and least-developed
countries will incur short-terms costs in the form of administration
and enforcement, and rent transfers, and that these will outweigh
the initial benefits. The cost-benefit balance will vary widely
from one country to another, but in many cases the costs will
be extremely burdensome.
(3) The dynamic nature of international IPR rule-making
IPRs, like other regulatory systems, are not
static but dynamic. During recent decades, there has been a
tendency for protectable subject matter to be widened, for new
rights to be created, and for the basic features of IPRs to
be standardized. Consequently, national IPR regimes throughout
the world are becoming increasingly held to harmonized minimum
standards of protection. While these standards remain a long
way from uniform law, this situation may be changing. Much of
the recent debate has focused on the TRIPS Agreement. TRIPS
seeks to establish enforceable universal minimum (and high)
standards of protection and enforcement for virtually all the
most important IPRs, but nonetheless allows for a certain amount
of diversity between different countries in terms of levels
of protection and exceptions.
Two other developments are also affecting the
evolution of IPR law at the international and national levels:
(1) new treaty development; and (2) harmonization. Taking the
first development, since the TRIPS Agreement entered into force
a number of new multilateral IPR treaties have been negotiated
and adopted. These include the WIPO Performances and Phonograms
Treaty, the WIPO Copyright Treaty, and the Patent Law Treaty.
Harmonization of substantive IPR law is coming about in two
ways. The first is through bilateral treaties between developed
and developing countries which tend to require standards of
protection to be on the same level as the developed country
party and with narrowed-down exceptions. The second is through
international and bilateral technical cooperation. There are
concerns that such cooperation does not fully take into account
the development needs of beneficiary countries nor the flexibilities
allowed to them under TRIPS. Another emerging force for harmonization
in the area of patent law is WIPO's draft Substantive Patent
Law Treaty.
In sum, harmonization is likely to entail making
the patent systems of the world more like each other using those
of the technologically most advanced countries as the models.
The effects of developments (1) and (2) overlap in the sense that
both are raising the floor of minimum IPR standards above the
level of the TRIPS Agreement and are therefore 'TRIPS plus'. The
implications for developing countries are two-fold. First, their
options are being rapidly narrowed. Second, because they have
to be aware of related developments taking place in a wide range
of forums and know where their national interest lies with respect
to each one, the development of coherent, effective and sustainable
policies and negotiating strategies on IPRs is becoming harder
than ever before. Ensuring consistency between the positions adopted
at the multilateral, regional and bilateral levels, and with national
IPR regulations is an enormous challenge and a tall order for
any country. In the case of developing countries and least developing
countries, it might constitute an impossible endeavour.
|